Jump to content

John Harsanyi

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

This is the current revision of this page, as edited by Monkbot (talk | contribs) at 04:17, 3 November 2024 (Task 20: replace {lang-??} templates with {langx|??} ‹See Tfd› (Replaced 1);). The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this version.

(diff) ← Previous revision | Latest revision (diff) | Newer revision → (diff)

John Harsanyi
Born
János Károly Harsányi

(1920-05-29)May 29, 1920
DiedAugust 9, 2000(2000-08-09) (aged 80)
Citizenship
  • Hungary
  • United States
Alma materUniversity of Lyon
University of Budapest
University of Sydney
Stanford University
Known forBayesian games
Utilitarian ethics
Equilibrium selection
SpouseAnne Klauber
AwardsNobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (1994)
John von Neumann Award
Scientific career
FieldsEconomics
InstitutionsUniversity of California, Berkeley
Wayne State University
Australian National University
University of Queensland
Doctoral advisorKenneth Arrow

John Charles Harsanyi (Hungarian: Harsányi János Károly; May 29, 1920 – August 9, 2000) was a Hungarian-American economist who spent most of his career at the University of California, Berkeley. He was the recipient of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1994.

Harsanyi is best known for his contributions to the study of game theory and its application to economics, specifically for his developing the highly innovative analysis of games of incomplete information, so-called Bayesian games. He also made important contributions to the use of game theory and economic reasoning in political and moral philosophy[1] (specifically utilitarian ethics[2]) as well as contributing to the study of equilibrium selection. For his work, he was a co-recipient along with John Nash and Reinhard Selten of the 1994 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences.

He moved to the United States in 1956, and spent most of his life there. According to György Marx, he was one of The Martians.[3]

Early life

[edit]

Harsanyi was born on May 29, 1920, in Budapest, Hungary, the son of Alice Harsányi (née Gombos) and Károly Harsányi, a pharmacy owner.[4] His parents converted from Judaism to Catholicism a year before he was born.[5] He attended high school at the Lutheran Gymnasium in Budapest. In high school, he became one of the best problem solvers of the KöMaL, the Mathematical and Physical Monthly for Secondary Schools. Founded in 1893, this periodical is generally credited with a large share of Hungarian students' success in mathematics. He also won the first prize in the Eötvös mathematics competition for high school students.[6]

Although he wanted to study mathematics and philosophy, his father sent him to France in 1939 to enroll in chemical engineering at the University of Lyon. However, because of the start of World War II, Harsanyi returned to Hungary to study pharmacology at the University of Budapest (today: Eötvös Loránd University), earning a diploma in 1944.[7] As a pharmacology student, Harsanyi escaped conscription into the Royal Hungarian Army which, as a person of Jewish descent, would have meant forced labor.

However, in 1944 (after the fall of the Horthy regime and the seizure of power by the Arrow Cross Party) his military deferment was cancelled and he was compelled to join a forced labor unit on the Eastern Front.[6][8] After seven months of forced labor, when the German authorities decided to deport his unit to a concentration camp in Austria, John Harsanyi managed to escape and found sanctuary for the rest of the war in a Jesuit house.[6][7][9]

Postwar

[edit]

After the end of the war, Harsanyi returned to the University of Budapest for graduate studies in philosophy and sociology, earning his PhD in both subjects in 1947. Then a devout Catholic, he simultaneously studied theology, also joining lay ranks of the Dominican Order. He later abandoned Catholicism, becoming an atheist for the rest of his life.[7] Harsanyi spent the academic year 1947–1948 on the faculty of the Institute of Sociology of the University of Budapest, where he met Anne Klauber, his future wife. He was forced to resign the faculty because of openly expressing his anti-Marxist opinions, while Anne faced increasing peer pressure to leave him for the same reason.

Harsanyi remained in Hungary for the following two years attempting to sell his family's pharmacy without losing it to the authorities. After it became apparent that the communist party would confiscate the pharmacy in 1950, he fled with Anne and her parents by illegally crossing the border into Austria and then going to Australia where Klauber's parents had some friends.[6][7][10]

Australia

[edit]

The two did not marry until they arrived in Australia because Klauber's immigration papers would need to be changed to reflect her married name. The two arrived with her parents on December 30, 1950, and they looked to marry immediately. Harsanyi and Klauber were married on January 2, 1951. Neither spoke much English and understood little of what they were told to say to each other. Harsanyi later explained to his new wife that she had promised to cook better food than she usually did.[10]

Harsanyi's Hungarian degrees were not recognized in Australia, but they earned him credit at the University of Sydney for a master's degree. Harsanyi worked in a factory during the day and studied economics in the evening at the University of Sydney, finishing with a M.A. in 1953. While studying in Sydney, he started publishing research papers in economic journals, including the Journal of Political Economy and the Review of Economic Studies. The degree allowed him to take a teaching position in 1954 at the University of Queensland in Brisbane.[7] While in Brisbane, Harsanyi's wife became a fashion designer for a small factory.[10]

Later years

[edit]

In 1956, Harsanyi received a Rockefeller scholarship that enabled him and Anne to spend the next two years in the United States, at Stanford University and, for a semester, at the Cowles Foundation. At Stanford Harsanyi wrote a dissertation in game theory under the supervision of Kenneth Arrow, earning a second PhD in economics in 1959, while Anne earned an MA in psychology. Harsanyi's student visa expired in 1958 and the two returned to Australia.

After working for a short time as a researcher at the Australian National University in Canberra, Harsanyi became frustrated with the lack of interest in game theory in Australia. With the help of Kenneth Arrow and James Tobin, he was able to move to the United States, taking a position as professor of economics at the Wayne State University in Detroit between 1961 and 1963. In 1964, he moved to Berkeley, California; he remained at the University of California, Berkeley, until retiring in 1990. Shortly after arriving in Berkeley, he and Anne had a child, Tom.

While teaching at Berkeley, Harsanyi did extensive research in game theory. Harold Kuhn, who had been John von Neumann's student in Princeton and already had games theory publications encouraged him in this. The work for which he won the 1994 Nobel Prize in economics was a series of articles published in 1967 and 1968 which established what has become the standard framework for analyzing "games of incomplete information", situations in which the various strategic decisionmakers have different information about the parameters of the game. He resolved the problem of how players could make decisions while not knowing what each other knows by modelling the situation with initial moves by Nature using known probabilities to choose the parameters, with some players observing Nature's move but other players just knowing the probabilities and the fact that some players have observed the actual realized values. This relies on assuming that all players know the structure of the game, which means they all have "common priors", knowing the probabilities Nature uses in selecting parameters values, an assumption known as the Harsanyi Doctrine.[11]

From 1966 to 1968, Harsanyi was part of a team of game theorists tasked with advising the United States Arms Control and Disarmament Agency in collaboration with Mathematica, a consulting group from Princeton University led by Harold Kuhn and Oskar Morgenstern.[6][7]

John Harsanyi died on August 9, 2000, from a heart attack in Berkeley, California, after developing Alzheimer's disease.[7]

Tribute

[edit]

On 29 May 2010, Google celebrated John Harsányi's Birthday with a doodle.[12][13]

Publications

[edit]

Harsanyi began researching utilitarian ethics in the mid-fifties at the University of Queensland in Brisbane. This led to two publications explaining why, before understanding moral problems, the difference between people's personal and moral preferences must be distinguished.[10] As he says at the beginning of his essay included in the book edited by A. Sen and B. Williams (see below), he tries to reconcile three traditions of Western moral thinking, those of Adam Smith, Immanuel Kant and the utilitarians (Bentham, Mill, Sidgwick and Edgeworth). He is considered one of the most important exponents of the "rule utilitarianism".

After moving to the US on a Rockefeller Fellowship where he was supervised by Kenneth Arrow, Harsanyi was influenced by Nash's publications on game theory and became increasingly interested in the topic.[10]

  • Harsanyi, John C. (October 1953). "Cardinal utility in welfare economics and in the theory of risk-taking". Journal of Political Economy. 61 (5): 434–435. doi:10.1086/257416. JSTOR 1827289. S2CID 222439814. Pdf. Archived April 23, 2021, at the Wayback Machine
  • Harsanyi, John C. (August 1955). "Cardinal welfare, individualistic ethics, and interpersonal comparisons of utility". Journal of Political Economy. 63 (4): 309–321. doi:10.1086/257678. JSTOR 1827128. S2CID 222434288. Pdf.
  • Harsanyi, John C. (March 1962). "Bargaining in ignorance of the opponent's utility function" (PDF). Journal of Conflict Resolution. 6 (1): 29–38. doi:10.1177/002200276200600104. JSTOR 172875. S2CID 153707897.
  • Harsanyi, John C. (November 1967). "Games with incomplete information played by "Bayesian" players, I-III. part I. The Basic Model". Management Science. 14 (3): 159–182. doi:10.1287/mnsc.14.3.159. JSTOR 2628393.
  • Harsanyi, John C. (1976). Essays on ethics, social behavior, and scientific explanation. Dordrecht, Holland Boston: D. Reidel Pub. Co. ISBN 9782266001656.
  • Harsanyi, John C. (1977). Rational behavior and bargaining equilibrium in games and social situations. Cambridge England New York: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521208864. Harsanyi, John C. (1986). 1st paperback edition. CUP Archive. ISBN 9780521311830.
  • Harsanyi, John C. (Winter 1977). "Morality and the theory of rational behavior". Social Research. 44 (4): 623–656. JSTOR 40971169.
Reprinted as: Harsanyi, John C. (1982), "Morality and the theory of rational behaviour", in Sen, Amartya; Williams, Bernard (eds.), Utilitarianism and beyond, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 39–62, ISBN 9780511611964.

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ Karni, Edi; Weymark, John A. (May 1, 1998). "An informationally parsimonious impartial observer theorem". Social Choice and Welfare. 15 (3): 321–332. doi:10.1007/s003550050108. ISSN 1432-217X.
  2. ^ "Economics Faculty Directory". emlab.Berkeley.edu. Archived from the original on November 23, 2007. Retrieved December 2, 2017.
  3. ^ A marslakók legendája – György Marx
  4. ^ "Harsanyi, John Charles – Dictionary definition of Harsanyi, John Charles – Encyclopedia.com: FREE online dictionary". www.Encyclopedia.com. Retrieved December 2, 2017.
  5. ^ "Biographical Memoirs Home" (PDF). www.NAP.edu. National Academy of Sciences. Retrieved December 2, 2017.
  6. ^ a b c d e John C. Harsanyi on Nobelprize.org Edit this at Wikidata, accessed 20201011
  7. ^ a b c d e f g Weymark, John A. (2006). "John Charles Harsanyi" (PDF). Working Paper No. 06-W07.
  8. ^ "Nobel Laureate John C. Harsanyi, UC Berkeley economist and game theory pioneer, dies at 80", HAAS News, UC at Berkeley
  9. ^ "John Harsanyi (1920–2000)" by Ariel Scheib, Jewish Virtual Library
  10. ^ a b c d e Breit, William; Hirsch, Barry T. (2004). Lives of the Laureates (4th ed.). Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press. ISBN 978-0-262-02562-1.
  11. ^ Bayesian Games: Games with Incomplete Information," Shmuel Zamir, 426–441, http://www.ma.huji.ac.il/~zamir/documents/BayesianGames_ShmuelZamir.pdf.
  12. ^ Desk, OV Digital (May 28, 2023). "29 May: Remembering John Harsányi on Birthday". Observer Voice. Retrieved May 28, 2023. {{cite web}}: |last= has generic name (help)
  13. ^ "John Harsányi's Birthday". www.google.com. Retrieved May 28, 2023.
  14. ^ Binmore, Ken (September 1989). "Reviewed Work: A General Theory of Equilibrium Selection in Games by John C. Harsanyi & Reinhard Selten". Journal of Economic Literature. 27 (3): 1171–1173. JSTOR 2726785.
[edit]
Awards
Preceded by Laureate of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics
1994
Served alongside: John F. Nash Jr., Reinhard Selten
Succeeded by